Books and documents:
Agustí Chalaux de Subirà, Brauli Tamarit Tamarit.
Agustí Chalaux de Subirà.
Agustí Chalaux de Subirà.
Agustí Chalaux de Subirà.
Magdalena Grau, Agustí Chalaux.
Martí Olivella.
|
|
Chapter 21. Background and empirical confirmations.
- Background.
- Empirical confirmations.
1. Background.
The hypothesis of a communal utilitarianism or of a commercial common
good in fact is no piece of news.
Careful studies could demonstrate that already Plato had in some way
sensed the possibility of sharing the private wealth present in the private
market.
Marx
himself, when he formulated the idea of increased value, was on its tracks,
but he limited himself to make the analysis of the micro-mercantile processes,
while the mercantile common good can only be comprehended in a macro-mercantile
overview.
But when the present-day economists mention the residual market value,
it is clear that they are fully touching on the subject. By residual
factor a production factor is meant which explains all that production
part which cannot be explained through the classical production factors.
This part is the highest when a country is more technologically and culturally
advanced.
Now, the attempts to a strict quantification of the residual factor
have always failed, through lack of a suitable measuring instrument.
Our modest claim is to offer the measuring instrument of the elemental
phenomena of the monetary market and society, which will allow to rigorously
formulate the hypothesis and to be able to experimentally confirm or invalidate
it.
2. Empirical confirmations.
Besides the theoretical background of the hypothesis of the mercantile
common good which we have just mentioned, this hypothesis has an empirical
basis of facts, evident to the eyes of the least prepared observer, which
represent an almost palpable demonstration which grants it a high degree
of probability, independently from the necessary pro-scientific experimentation.
We refer, fundamentally, to three great facts, of an enormous range
and extension in our century, mainly in the countries most progressively
industrialized:
-
The actual existence on the markets of great amounts of production surpluses,
unsaleable because of the lack of purchasing power -both by the companies
and by the consumers, both by the developed countries and by the poorest
countries-.
-
The vertiginous growth of the public debt of all contemporary States.
This public debt is the appropriation of the common good by the State:
it consists of the invention by each Bank and by its Central Bank of a
purchasing power which will be used to face the budgetary needs, but which
is based on the real productive abilities of the whole geopolitical community
-because, if it were not so, these communities, with the very high public
debt of their States, would have been totally broke for a long time-.
-
The fabulous enrichment of bankers and of multinational companies. Both
of them have also the ability, not controlled by anybody, to invent purchasing
power by many means. This invention takes also advantage of the productive
overabundance of the geopolitical community -caused by the non payment
of the communal production agents-, but often it surpasses it, therefore
driving the whole community to situations of crisis which only damage the
small or medium consumers, and with which these large sharks of finances
make a fortune.
Of these three facts, the first one is a demonstration of the mercantile
common good on a production level.
The other two are clearly demonstrations as far as money availability
is concerned: the legitimate payment owed to the communal production forces
is diverted and taken for the state budgets and for the bank's and mutinationals'
profits. But since the knowledge of the mercantile common good is not perfect,
this diversion, besides being unfair in most cases, it is also imperfect,
either for excess or for want, and creates imbalances known as inflation
and deflation crises.
|